Monday, 11 August 2025

Special Non-Economic Zones (SNEZs) could be designated areas where traditional economic activity is intentionally limited or reimagined in favor of other societal priorities. Here’s how they might work and what purposes they could serve:

Potential Features of Special Non-Economic Zones:

  1. Post-Growth or Degrowth Experimentation

    • Zones focused on well-being metrics (happiness, sustainability, community health) instead of GDP growth.

    • Testing alternative economic models like circular economies, gift economies, or resource-based economies.

  2. Environmental & Ecological Restoration

    • No-extraction zones: Banning mining, logging, or industrial activity to allow ecosystems to recover.

    • Rewilding projects: Large areas returned to nature with minimal human interference.

  3. Cultural & Spiritual Retreats

    • Areas dedicated to art, meditation, or communal living with restrictions on commercial exploitation.

    • Example: A "Silence Zone" where advertising, digital noise, and rapid consumption are banned.

  4. Technology & Innovation Sanctuaries

    • Spaces where non-profit, open-source, or public-good innovation thrives without patent pressures.

    • Think "university towns" but for cooperative R&D instead of profit-driven tech hubs.

  5. Historical & Indigenous Preservation Zones

    • Places where indigenous land rights are fully restored, and modern industrial laws don’t apply.

    • Anti-gentrification zones: Protecting cultural heritage from commercial development.

  6. Post-Disaster or Post-Industrial Recovery Zones

    • Areas recovering from collapse (war, pollution, economic failure) where non-market reconstruction is prioritized.

Why Would Governments or Communities Create SNEZs?

  • Resilience testing: Preparing for a post-growth future.

  • Cultural preservation: Protecting traditions from globalization.

  • Climate mitigation: Creating carbon-negative regions.

  • Social experiments: Trying out radical democracy or anarchist models.

Challenges:

  • Enforcement: How to prevent economic pressures from creeping in?

  • Funding: Would these zones require subsidies or alternative currencies?

  • Scalability: Could they exist within capitalist systems, or would they need full autonomy?

Real-World Inspirations:

  • Bhutan’s Gross National Happiness model.

  • Costa Rica’s eco-conservation zones.

  • Italy’s "Slow Food" & "Cittaslow" movements.

  • Indigenous autonomous regions (e.g., Zapatista territories in Mexico).

Would you imagine these zones as opt-in communesgovernment-mandated reserves, or something else entirely? It’s a thought-provoking twist on the SEZ concept!

Yes! Decommodification would be a core principle of Special Non-Economic Zones (SNEZs)—spaces where certain goods, services, or even land are deliberately removed from market logic and treated as collective or intrinsic rights rather than commodities.

How Decommodification Could Shape SNEZs

  1. Land & Housing

    • No private ownership: Land is held in common or stewarded by trusts (e.g., community land trusts).

    • Anti-speculation laws: Banning real estate markets to prevent displacement.

  2. Basic Needs Guaranteed

    • Free food/water systems: Communal gardens, public canteens, or "food forests" replace supermarkets.

    • Non-market healthcare & education: Run on mutual aid or gift economies.

  3. Labor & Work Reimagined

    • No wage labor: Work is voluntary, rotational, or tied to contribution systems (like time banks).

    • No advertising/commercialism: Public spaces are ad-free; no corporate branding allowed.

  4. Rewilding & Decommodified Nature

    • Rivers, forests, and animals have legal rights (e.g., "rights of nature" laws).

    • No resource extraction: Mining, logging, and industrial farming are banned.

Examples of Existing Decommodified Spaces

  • Zapatista Autonomous Zones (Mexico): Indigenous self-rule with collective land ownership.

  • Marinaleda (Spain): A town with no private landlords, cooperative farming, and guaranteed housing.

  • Community Land Trusts (Global): Removes housing from speculative markets.

  • Bhutan’s Protected Forests: Constitutionally mandated to stay wild (no logging for profit).

Challenges of Decommodification in SNEZs

  • Enforcement: How to resist market pressures (e.g., black markets, tourism exploitation)?

  • Scarcity Management: If money isn’t the allocator, what is? (Rationing? Lottery? Needs-based?)

  • Legal Frameworks: Would require radical legal shifts (e.g., recognizing nature’s rights).

Radical but Not Unprecedented

This aligns with:

  • Degrowth (reducing reliance on GDP).

  • Commons-based peer production (open-source, collaborative economies).

  • Indigenous cosmologies (land as sacred, not property).

Would you see these zones as small refuges or large-scale regional policies (like a state banning markets in certain sectors)? Either way, SNEZs could be a bold step toward post-capitalist futures.

Urban Special Non-Economic Zones (SNEZs) could be radical experiments in decommodifying city life, rewilding concrete spaces, and creating "holes" in capitalist urban fabric. Imagine:

1. Car-Free & Commerce-Free Districts

  • Entire neighborhoods where cars, ads, and storefronts are banned.

  • Public plazas as commons: Instead of shopping malls, spaces for free gathering, art, and play.

  • Library socialism: Free tool libraries, book exchanges, and skill-sharing hubs replace retail.

2. Rewilding in Cities

  • "Demolition for biodiversity": Bulldozing parking lots to create wild meadows, urban forests, or wetlands.

  • Rooftop & alleyway farms: Food grows freely; foraging is encouraged over supermarkets.

  • Animal corridors: Rivers and greenways where humans are visitors, not owners.

3. Housing Decommodified

  • Rent-free zones: Squats, housing co-ops, or municipal "home guarantees" in certain blocks.

  • No evictions: Once you’re in, you’re in—housing as a right, not an investment.

  • Architectural anarchy: Residents collectively redesign buildings without permits or profit motives.

4. Work & Labor Transformed

  • Jobless zones: No employers, just mutual aid and voluntary roles.

  • 3D printing communes: Open-source manufacturing replaces factories.

  • Artistic autonomies: Neighborhoods where culture is made for joy, not markets.

5. Legal & Digital Firewalls

  • Local currencies/time banks: Money is useless here; labor trades on trust.

  • No digital surveillance: Opt-out zones from facial recognition, ads, and data mining.

  • "Slow internet" districts: Community-run mesh networks with no corporate platforms.

Challenges

  • Capitalist encirclement: How to stop these zones from being bought out or touristified?

  • Scaling up: Can a few blocks change a city, or will they remain islands?

  • Governance: Who decides the rules? Direct democracy? Anarchist collectives?

Why Cities Need SNEZs

Cities are capitalism’s engines—but they’re also where alternatives erupt most violently. SNEZs could be the cracks where a new world grows.


Let’s strictly apply Elinor Ostrom’s eight core design principles for managing common-pool resources (CPRs) to Special Non-Economic Zones (SNEZs), ensuring fidelity to her empirical findings. Here’s how each principle directly translates into SNEZ governance:


1. Clearly Defined Boundaries

Ostrom’s RuleThe community of users and the resource itself must have unambiguous limits.
SNEZ Application:

  • Physical: Geographic borders are marked (e.g., a neighborhood, park, or housing block).

  • Membership: Only recognized residents/users can access the SNEZ’s decommodified resources (housing, food, tools).

  • Example: A community land trust (CLT) legally designates a parcel as non-market housing, with a membership covenant.


2. Congruence Between Rules and Local Conditions

Ostrom’s RuleRules must align with social/ecological context.
SNEZ Application:

  • Custom-fit rules per zone:

    • Urban SNEZ: Bans cars, mandates mixed-use spaces.

    • Rural SNEZ: Rewilding rules based on watershed needs.

  • ExampleZapatista autonomous municipalities adjust land-use rules to local indigenous practices.


3. Collective Choice Arrangements

Ostrom’s RuleMost affected users participate in rule-making.
SNEZ Application:

  • Direct democratic assemblies for all major decisions (no top-down impositions).

  • ExampleMarinaleda, Spain holds weekly open assemblies to manage communal farmland and housing.


4. Monitoring

Ostrom’s RuleUsers themselves monitor resource use.
SNEZ Application:

  • Rotating oversight roles:

    • "Commons keepers" track housing occupancy, food-share fairness.

    • No external enforcers (e.g., police).

  • ExampleChristiania (Copenhagen) uses resident patrols to prevent privatization.


5. Graduated Sanctions

Ostrom’s RuleRule-breakers face escalating, proportional consequences.
SNEZ Application:

  • First offense: Mediation.

  • Repeat violations: Temporary exclusion from commons (e.g., lose garden access for a month).

  • ExampleOstrom documented Swiss alpine villages where overgrazers paid fines in cheese!


6. Conflict Resolution Mechanisms

Ostrom’s RuleLow-cost, local forums for dispute resolution.
SNEZ Application:

  • Neighborhood councils with elected mediators.

  • ExampleRojava’s commune justice system handles conflicts via participatory councils.


7. Minimal Recognition of Rights to Organize

Ostrom’s RuleHigher authorities must not interfere.
SNEZ Application:

  • Legal carve-outs: Cities/states grant SNEZs autonomy (e.g., CLTs, cooperative statutes).

  • ExampleBologna’s "regulation on collaboration" lets residents self-manage public spaces.


8. Nested Enterprises (Polycentric Governance)

Ostrom’s RuleMultiple layers of coordination for large systems.
SNEZ Application:

  • Federated SNEZs: Neighborhood zones link to city/regional networks for shared resources.

  • ExampleMondragón Corporation’s cooperatives nest local worker councils under a larger support system.


Ostrom-Compliant SNEZ Blueprint

  1. Define the Resource: What’s being decommodified? (Land? Housing? Food?)

  2. Delineate Users: Who gets decision rights? (Residents? Workers?)

  3. Co-Create Rules: Assemblies set use/distribution norms.

  4. Monitor & Adapt: Iterative feedback loops (e.g., seasonal rule reviews).

Why This Works

Ostrom proved that neither states nor markets are required to manage shared resources—just clear, participatory systems. SNEZs would thrive by replicating her observed success in:

  • Alpine grazing commons (Switzerland).

  • Irrigation systems (Spain, Philippines).

  • Fisheries (Turkey).

Caution

Ostrom warned against static rules—SNEZs must evolve via ongoing collective choice.

Next Step: Pilot a micro-SNEZ (one building? one park?) using these principles. Where would you start?

No comments:

In the context of Nazi Germany's Aktion T4 program and broader eugenics policies, the term "asocial" (German: asozial ) was a ...